Friday27 December 2024
sportivnayarossiya.com

Achieving the best outcome in any situation involves understanding Nash equilibrium and the prisoner's dilemma.

Crucial political negotiations, Friday game nights with friends, and the rivalry between major business competitors—all of these are just games where the stakes are incredibly high. To carve out your own niche in the world, you must... maintain balance. We explain what Nash equilibrium is and delve into the dilemma faced by the prisoner.
Как достичь оптимального результата в любом деле: равновесие Нэша и проблема заключенного.

Game Theory

Unfortunately, this won’t include cheat codes for GTA or secret moves for Ghost of Tsushima.

Game theory is a branch of mathematics that analyzes the strategies of interaction between two or more parties and the consequences of their decisions. In this context, a game represents a clash of interests, and the players don’t necessarily have to be human!

An opponent in the game could be a program or even an abstract category, such as market demand.

In other words, it is a scientific approach to studying human interactions, attempting to explain it as a game with a specific set of combinations for each side. Any decision sets the entire system into motion and affects the outcome of the game itself. Naturally, the ultimate goal is to find a winning strategy.

Every individual thinks through the steps to achieve their goals. However, game theory also takes into account the moves of opponents, their intentions, possible countermeasures, and even how competitors can reach a favorable outcome. It’s a valuable concept!

Соперники в шахматах5 Freepik

The founder of game theory is generally considered to be the Hungarian-American mathematician John von Neumann. In 1944, he published a work titled “Theory of Games and Economic Behavior” along with economist Oskar Morgenstern (yes, that’s amusing).

Соперники в шахматах6 John von NeumannWikiCommons

Primarily, Neumann studied what are known as “zero-sum games.” These are situations where the winner takes all that the other players lose, making cooperation among competitors impossible. The total of wins and losses equals zero.

The simplest example of such a situation is poker or any other gambling game, where the winner takes the bets from other players.

Соперники в шахматах7 pokercm.com

However, the name most synonymous with game theory is that of American mathematician and Nobel laureate John Nash.

Equilibrium and the Nobel Prize: John Nash

As a young student, John did not like mathematics at all. Yet, by the age of 21, he wrote a paper for which he would later receive the Nobel Prize in Economics 45 years later.

Соперники в шахматах8 John NashWikiCommons

Nash’s idea was both simple and brilliant. He proved that there are many instances where the total of wins and losses is far from zero. Outcomes can occur where the total is below zero (everyone loses), as well as where the total is above zero (the majority wins).

The issues that game theory specialists tackled in the 1950s and 60s revolved around nuclear deterrence and arms races.

John Nash challenged even Adam Smith by disproving his assertion that competition is the main fuel of the market. The mathematician demonstrated that the strategy of “each person in the group does what is best for them” ultimately implies only one winner from the entire group. Moreover, there is a possibility that no one ends up winning.

However, if participants are concerned not only with their own interests but also with the group's goals, each of them has a chance to gain their share of the overall success.

Соперники в шахматах9 Freepik

Nash also proved that in every competitive game, there exists an equilibrium.

Nash equilibrium is a state of a game where no player can benefit from changing their strategy unilaterally if the others do not change theirs. “The discovery of the concept of equilibrium in economic science is comparable in significance to the discovery of the double helix of DNA in biology.” Джон фон Нейман0 Roger Myerson American economist, Nobel laureate in Economics 2007

The Prisoner’s Dilemma

So, here’s the situation. Two criminals are caught at the same time for similar crimes. The investigation believes they acted in collusion, but there is no direct evidence. The police isolate them from each other and offer the same deal. If one testifies against the other while the other remains silent, the first is released for assisting the investigation, while the second receives 10 years in prison. If both remain silent, their actions are treated under a lesser charge, and they serve one year in prison. If both prisoners testify against each other, each receives two years in prison.

Джон фон Нейман1 Illustration of the "Prisoner's Dilemma" ©MIPT Press Service / Author: Artem Fomin

Each prisoner has a choice — to remain silent or to testify against the other. Neither knows for sure how their unfortunate companion will act. The most advantageous option is to take the risk and stay silent, hoping for cooperation from the accomplice. But how would any rational person behave? They probably wouldn’t end up in prison... But what if they did?

The most rational option is, of course, to betray the accomplice and start talking. This is the only way to avoid the maximum sentence regardless of the partner's actions. Ultimately, the entire strategy boils down to minimizing one’s own risks, while the most favorable outcome would arise only from considering the common good.

The Prisoner’s Dilemma illustrates that acting solely in one’s self-interest does not always guarantee the best outcome.

Common sense helps us avoid strange situations. Well, if you do find yourself in one — mathematics will help you emerge from any situation in the best possible light!

Admit it, what would you do if you were in the prisoner’s position? Silence is golden! Rat out another and you won’t be judged... I’m a cop